ECB Turning into a “Bad Bank”? Nonsense

Holger Schmieding

Berenberg Bank

Dr Holger Schmieding is Chief Economist at Berenberg in London. Before joining Berenberg in October 2010, Holger worked as Chief Economist Europe at Merrill Lynch, Bank of America and Bank of America-Merrill Lynch in London. Having studied economics in Munich, London and Kiel, he holds a doctorate from the University of Kiel. Prior to this, he also worked as a journalist at Westfälische Nachrichten in Germany, as head of a research group on east-central Europe at the Kiel Institute of World Economics and as a desk economist at the International Monetary Fund in Washington, DC.

Adequate ECB Policy Reduces Risks

For five years, many German academics and the mass media have warned that the unconventional policies of the European Central Bank (ECB) would lead to higher inflation. Year after year, the facts have proven them wrong. Inflation has fallen to just 0.3 percent for the euro zone instead. Even Germany has never before enjoyed such a long period of stable low inflation than it has since the ECB took over the reins of monetary policy at the end of 1998.

Now the doom mongers are warning that the ECB is turning itself into a “bad bank,” potentially placing a huge burden on German taxpayers who – via the Bundesbank share in the ECB – de facto own 27 percent of the ECB. Once again, these experts are getting their logic upside down. The opposite of what they claim is correct: by pursuing an adequate policy as required by its mandate, the ECB is helping to reduce risks for all taxpayers in the euro zone, including the German taxpayers. Among the mistakes the ECB critics make, they seem to fall victim to a “lump of risk fallacy.”

What is behind the claim that the ECB is now turning into a bad bank? The ECB has decided to pursue a more expansionary monetary policy by purchasing asset-backed securities (ABS) and covered bonds, potentially to the tune of €300 billion. The ECB decision makes sense. Inflation is far below the de facto target of 1.9 percent. The confidence shock of Putin’s aggression against Ukraine and other geopolitical risks have dealt a significant blow to the near-term outlook for the euro zone economy. Nothing in the current data points to a major rise in inflation in the coming years. In such a situation, the ECB’s mandate requires the bank to inject additional stimulus in order to get inflation closer to target over time. With interest rates already close to 0 percent and with generous conditions for the ECB’s conventional refinancing operations, asset purchases are the logical next step for the ECB. If the ECB simply stayed put while the economy weakened and inflation continued to undershoot the target, the ECB would violate its mandate.

Good News for Taxpayers

But what will ECB asset purchases mean for taxpayers? Simple answer: it’s good news for taxpayers. The ECB will buy interest-bearing assets in exchange for central bank money which the ECB can create at virtually zero cost. As a result, the ECB will earn an extra profit, which will largely accrue to the national central banks of its member countries. Once the Bundesbank distributes these extra profits to the German federal budget, the German taxpayers will benefit directly.

But won’t the ECB incur huge risks by buying dodgy bonds, the kind of bonds that once contributed to the U.S. sub-prime crisis ? This oft-heard assertion is wrong. U.S.-style “sub-prime” mortgage bonds barely exist in the euro zone. For all structured finance assets in Europe, the default rate from the beginning of the U.S. financial crisis in July 2007 throughout the post-Lehman and then the euro crisis until late 2013 was a mere 1.5 percent. For the major asset that the ECB will actually buy, so-called residential mortgage-backed securities (RMBS), the European default rate was just 0.1 percent. Consumer finance asset-backed securities, which the ECB will also purchase, had a default rate of just 0.04 percent. That compares to an 18.4 percent default rate for ABS on U.S. loans including subprime loans during that period. Throughout the worst of the financial crises, the default rate in Europe on the kind of assets the ECB will buy was extremely low. To use the post-2007 U.S. experience with dodgy U.S. paper to discredit the ECB’s plans to buy the very different private-sector securities available in the euro zone is grossly misleading, to put it mildly.

In addition, the ECB will employ some important safeguards. First, ECB purchases will focus on investment-grade paper. More than 90 percent of the rated securities in the €1.5 billion European securitizations market have investment grade credit ratings. Second, the ECB will only buy paper that is structured in a transparent way, again reducing risks. Third, while the ECB will buy small amounts of paper from Greece and Cyprus without an investment-grade rating, the ECB will do so only if these countries stay in an EU-supervised adjustment program to strengthen their economies and hence contain the risks.

The “Lump of Risk” Fallacy

Most importantly, the critics accusing the ECB of potentially burdening German taxpayers with big losses make what is a beginner’s mistake in economic analysis. We can call it the “lump of risk” fallacy. They seem to assume that “risk” is a constant that can only be redistributed. So if the ECB now buys securities, the ECB would take the risk off the balance sheets of the banks and private investors selling the paper and take the same risk onto its own balance sheet, to the potential detriment of the taxpayers who are the ultimate owners of the ECB. That misses the major point: risk is not a constant that can only be redistributed. An adequate central bank policy reduces the risks of recession and financial crises.

In the current environment, a further monetary stimulus is required to stabilize confidence and support weak demand in the euro zone. Otherwise, the risk that the euro zone, including Germany, may fall into recession would be significant. For taxpayers, recessions with their rise in unemployment and fall in tax revenues are very expensive. By adding a further monetary stimulus, the ECB lowers the overall level of risk in the euro zone and German economy. Incidentally, an adequate monetary policy also reduces further the very low default rate for the kind of assets which the ECB will buy. The ECB policy is geared toward meeting its mandate. This policy will benefit and not harm the German taxpayer.

This essay appears originally in “Macro News,” (PDF) the newsletter of Joh. Berenberg, Gossler & Co..and is reprinted here with the permission of the author, Holger Schmieding, Chief Economist.

The views expressed are those of the author(s) alone. They do not necessarily reflect the views of the American-German Institute.